Fri, 26 Nov 2004

Labor in a world of financial capitalism

Robert J. Shiller Project Syndicate

The traditional hostility between labor unions and the world of finance should not obscure their common interest in using financial tools in an expansive and creative way. We live in an age of financial capitalism, and the only intelligent way forward -- for unions and other workers' associations -- is for these bodies to help their members make increasingly sophisticated use of the tools of risk management.

The traditional boundaries between labor and capital are becoming blurred. For example, companies increasingly augment standard wage packages with stock options, even for rank-and-file employees. In the United States, the Labor Department reports that in 2003, 14 percent of U.S. workers in firms with 100 or more employees were offered stock options. Expect more such packages in the future.

The problem is, most employees do not fully understand options or stocks and do not know how to evaluate them. A recent paper by MIT Professors Nittai Bergman and Derk Jenter suggests that management tends to award employee options when employees are excessively optimistic about the outlook for company stock -- thereby in effect opportunistically substituting overpriced options for full pay.

Unions and workers associations are the natural vehicles to monitor such behavior, but they must invest in the expertise to do so effectively. They should not stand in the way of compensation that includes stock options, or that otherwise create financial risks for their employees. But they should make sure that such programs are administered in employees' interest, because companies that encourage their employees to hold options or to invest directly in the company's stock are asking them to take on some of the company's risks.

To be sure, sharing ownership can help employee morale. But it also creates an unhealthy concentration of risks: Not only the employee's job, but also his assets now depend on the company's fate. The scandal at Enron, in its final days, was that management prevented employees from selling their Enron shares while executives unloaded their own shares.

Obviously, unions need to be alert to such bad behavior. More generally, they must examine employee ownership programs both sympathetically and analytically, in order to suggest ways to hedge the risks they create.

The same is true of other financial tools. Labor unions have long pointed with satisfaction at hard-won contracts that specified a defined-benefit pension for their members. But these unions were often without the financial sophistication to judge whether the firm set aside sufficient capital to meet its commitments decades later.

In the U.S., union failure to represent members' interests adequately contributed to a major pension default at the Studebaker Corporation in 1963. The AFL-CIO, the United Auto Workers and the United Steel Workers then petitioned Congress -- against strong opposition from business interests -- to establish the Pension Benefit Guaranty Corporation in 1974 to insure private pensions against companies' failure to honor them.

Gradually, many countries, with prodding from their trade unions, now have some form of benefit protection plan for private pensions. The latest example is the United Kingdom, where trade unions have spurred the creation of the Pension Protection Fund, which will begin operating next year.

But it is not clear that these plans will succeed fully. Declining stock markets and low interest rates, have left private pensions around the world more vulnerable than was expected. Moreover, the risks to pension funds may correlate with risks to other economic factors affecting specific groups of workers.

This means that unions should not leave the complex financial problems of designing pensions entirely to governments. Local unions need to be involved, for the issues involved are specific to companies and workers, and cannot be resolved by governments alone.

Indeed, the essence of labor unions is that they know the unique problems of a distinct group of workers, bring focused expertise on these problems, and thus intelligently represent their interests. In today's complex financial economies, representing workers' interests is not so simple as battling with management for a bigger share of the pie. Unions should instead negotiate with management the same way top executives do with their boards of directors when their complex compensation packages are worked out.

Unfortunately, instead of learning how to think in financially sophisticated ways, we still see labor unions in Europe and elsewhere dwelling too much on job security for working people. But making it difficult for firms to lay off workers provides only an illusory benefit for workers, for it compromises companies' ability to compete, and weakens their incentive to create jobs.

The alignment of incentives lies at the heart of modern financial theory. Labor unions should negotiate with management about providing appropriate risk management to their employees in financial forms: the right kinds of insurance, options, and other investments to protect them realistically without guaranteeing their employment and without jeopardizing the productivity of the firm.

Complex financial capitalism is here to stay, and we all have to learn to live with it. Union leaders must study finance rather than condemn it as evil. They must develop a cadre of professionals with a sophisticated understanding of risk management, and must work to educate their members in the financial subtleties of their specific circumstances.

The writer is Professor of Economics at Yale University, and author of Irrational Exuberance and The New Financial Order: Risk in the 21st Century.