Wed, 23 Feb 2005

China shows the way in a quota-free market

Linda Lim, Yale Center for the Study of Globalization, Ann Arbor, Michigan

The January 2005 termination of the three decades-old textile quotas have been met with anguished cries from affected countries, as well as calls to restrict exporters read: China: poised to dominate the world textile market. This populist call will not only hurt the interest of consumers, who would benefit from the lower cost of an unshackled market.

Instead of blocking Chinese exports, it would be better to learn from the Chinese example of smart investment and management to thrive in a globalized economy of "creative destruction."

In place since 1974, the Multi-Fiber Agreement (MFA) aimed to protect developed-country textile manufacturers, who had lost comparative advantage in this typically labor-intensive industry to poorer, and thus lower-wage, country competitors.

The MFA resulted in the proliferation of developing country textile and clothing exporters. As manufacturers reached quota limits in one exporting country, operations moved to countries not yet subject to quotas.

At the same time, quota protection predictably discouraged its beneficiaries in both developed and developing countries from improving their competitiveness. The chickens of their inattention have come home to roost, as many now see their market shares being gobbled up: China's share of the US$350 billion global textile market is expected to rise from its current 20 percent to a maximum of 60 percent in the coming years.

Today, China finds itself the target of post-quota protectionist efforts in countries -- developing as well as developed -- whose governments and industries failed to prepare for post-quota market challenges.

Underpinning the current controversy is the erroneous belief that China's competitiveness in textiles and garments derives from its inexhaustible supply of readily-exploited unskilled labor. Though China's labor certainly is cheap compared to developed countries', wages have been rising rapidly.

Labor shortages have appeared as economic growth spreads prosperity; many workers are returning to their countryside homes as farm incomes rise. Clothing industry wage rates (and overall labor costs) are already significantly higher in China than in Vietnam, Cambodia, Bangladesh, India, Sri Lanka, and Indonesia.

The Chinese textile industry's competitive advantages lie elsewhere.

First, Chinese workers are much more productive, probably because they are better-educated, better-motivated, and have better health status, given the legacies of the socialist state.

Second, Chinese factories benefit from economies of scale, given the large production base and domestic market afforded by the country's huge population.

Third, China's large, diverse, and increasingly integrated industrial base means that many materials required to make clothing are locally available, avoiding the added costs, risks, and longer delivery lead-times that imported imputs impose on other countries.

Fourth, China's geographical location, close to Japan, Korea, Taiwan, and Hong Kong, allows it to readily import advanced equipment and high-tech textiles for its finishing industries.

Fifth, the predominantly Hong Kong- and Taiwan-based manufacturers in the global industry may have language and cultural advantages managing Chinese workers, and thus may be willing to invest more in China.

Sixth, China has also invested heavily in its physical infrastructure, allowing speed of delivery of both imports and exports.

How, then, can other countries compete with China in the new quota-free world of textile and clothing trade? Capital-abundant, labor-scarce rich countries like the United States and Western Europe cannot have a comparative advantage in the labor-intensive end of the industry, despite their increasingly heavy reliance on lower-wage immigrant labor (including ethnic Chinese).

The obvious solution is to exit the industry, redeploying its capital and labor in higher-wage and more profitable sectors, or to relocate operations to more labor-abundant countries. Firms that wish to remain in the industry and stay at home can do so if they automate their technology and move into higher-value segments of the industry; these include new materials development, creative design and marketing -- which already account for a high proportion of the industry value chain -- and small-batch, customized, skill-intensive high-fashion wear that is more time- and less price-sensitive.

Developing countries located close to rich final markets (e.g. Central America) can also exploit their geographical proximity with short turnaround times in particular industry segments. Those close to China itself can piggy-back on some of their larger neighbor's locational advantages -- namely, favorable positioning in East Asia-wide supply chains. As such, they may act as preferred "second source" or "spillover" locations for manufacturers, including those from China itself.

Some developing countries may also have special advantages that set them apart from the competition. For instance, Cambodia has a reputation for good labor standards resulting from its bilateral textile agreement with the United States.

But these are mostly short-term advantages for developing countries competing with China in the textile and clothing export industry. These countries can sustain their longer-term competitiveness only by emulating China. That is, they need to invest in infrastructure, particularly transportation and logistics, and in training and management of workers to reduce turnaround time and improve labor productivity.

They must also lower their trade barriers to imported components, and reduce corruption and other "hidden costs." Further, improving quality, developing industry expertise and linkages to global buyers, and attracting international investors will broaden their export markets, providing access to scale economies.

These efforts require public (government) as well as private (business) resources and commitment, and in the end -- as in any market competition -- only some of the current country producers will survive. Without quotas, manufacturers and buyers would do well to consolidate production and purchasing in fewer locations, even as lower post-quota costs and consumer prices hold out the promise of increased sales.

The writer is Professor of Corporate Strategy and International Business at the University of Michigan Business School. Reprinted with permission from YaleGlobal Online, (http://yaleglobal.yale.edu).