Are we running out of oil again?
Robert J. Shiller, Project Syndicate
Oil prices are now running well above US$50 a barrel, partly owing to short-run supply shocks, such as the Iraq conflict, Nigerian labor disputes, the conflict between Yukos Oil and the Russian government, and Florida's recent hurricanes. Oil prices may fall once these shocks dissipate, but speculative effects could keep them relatively high, weakening the world economy and depressing stock markets.
Even a temporary spike in oil prices can have long-term effects because of the social reactions they provoke. High oil prices fuel public discussion about the future of oil prices. The outcome of any public discussion can never be known with certainty, but chances are that it will amplify stories that imply risks of higher oil prices. Experts may say that short-run supply factors caused the recent price increases, but the price increases will nonetheless lend credibility to scarier long-term stories.
The scary story that is being amplified now concerns the developing world, notably China and India, where rapid economic growth -- and no restrictions on emissions under the Kyoto Protocol -- are seen as creating insatiable demands for oil. The story's premise is that the world will run out of oil faster than we thought, as these billions of people chase their dreams of big houses and sport utility vehicles. Is this plausible?
Certainly, China, India, and some other emerging countries are developing fast. But experts find it difficult to specify the long-run implications of this for the energy market. Too many factors remain fuzzy: The rate of growth of these countries' energy demand, discoveries of new oil reserves, developments in oil-saving technology, and the ultimate replacement of oil by other energy sources.
But what matters for oil prices now and in the foreseeable future is the perception of the story, not the ambiguities behind it. If there is a perception that prices will be higher in the future, then prices will tend to be higher today. That is how markets work.
If it is generally thought that oil prices will be higher in the future, owners of oil reserves will tend to postpone costly investments in exploration and expansion of production capacity, and they may pump oil at below capacity. They would rather sell their oil and invest later, when prices are higher, so they restrain increases in supply. Expectations become self- fulfilling, oil prices rise, a speculative bubble is born.
But if owners of oil reserves think that prices will fall in the long run, they gain an incentive to explore for oil and expand production now in order to sell as much oil as possible before the fall. The resulting supply surge drives down prices, reinforces expectations of further declines, and produces the inverse of a speculative bubble: a collapse in prices.
All of this may seem obvious, but we tend not to think of oil prices as being determined by expectations of future prices. For example, in January 1974, when the first world oil crisis began, oil prices doubled in just days. The immediate cause was believed to have been Israel's stunning success in the Yom Kippur War, which led Arab oil producers to retaliate by choking off output. The second crisis, in 1979, is usually attributed to supply disruptions from the Persian Gulf following the Islamic revolution in Iran and the subsequent start of the Iran-Iraq war.
Why, then, did real inflation-corrected oil prices remain at or above their 1974 levels until 1986? Speculative pressures are likely to have been at work, influencing the decisions of OPEC and many others. Although changes in market psychology are difficult to understand, the broad concerns that underlie such episodes of irrational exuberance are almost always clear.
For example, in 1972, scientists at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology, including computer pioneer Jay Forrester, published The Limits to Growth. The book launched an international debate on whether the world would soon face immense economic problems due to shortages of oil and other natural resources -- problems that seemed to be presaged by OPEC's production cuts eighteen months later.
The second crisis was immediately preceded by the accident at the Three-Mile Island nuclear reactor in Pennsylvania in March 1979, which reinvigorated the anti-nuclear movement. With nuclear power -- regarded as the main technological bulwark against depletion of the world's oil supplies -- suddenly suspect, oil prices doubled again by the year's end.
After 1979, fears about limits to growth and nuclear power ebbed. Oil prices gradually fell, and the stock market began its long climb towards its peak in 2000.
But the current rise in oil prices shows that people are still eager to embrace "running out of oil" stories -- this time focused on China and India -- even when short-run factors are to blame. Indeed, the International Energy Agency noted in September that the usual relationship between oil prices and inventory levels has broken down, with prices much higher than the usual relationship would suggest.
The IEA's report calls this breakdown evidence of a "structural shift in the market." But the same pattern followed the 1973-1974 and 1979-1980 oil crises, when prices dropped from their highest peaks, but stayed quite high for years, representing a drag on the stock market, the housing market, and the world economy. Let's hope that the effects of the present spike will be more short-lived. But don't hold your breath.
The writer is Professor of Economics at Yale University, and author of Irrational Exuberance and The New Financial Order: Risk in the 21st Century.